Blog Layout

Housing and the Marxism question

A new book puts a Marxist frame around its picture of the Merseyside Housing Co-ops. How useful is that?

Reconstructing Public Housing is a book by Matthew Thompson about Liverpool's hidden history of alternative ways to build communities

Matthew Thompson’s book Reconstructing Public Housing (Liverpool University Press, 2020) considers the legacy of the Merseyside newbuild housing co-operatives. From the late nineteen seventies, groups of would-be tenants formed co-ops that chose land, appointed architects and commissioned their own new housing estates, funded by government grant for what we now call ‘social housing.’


Matthew makes great use of my thesis Citizenship and Consumption (University of Salford, 1998) with material drawn from my experience working with the inception of the new-build co-ops from 1977. He takes the story forward to today’s successor organisations, including Community Land Trusts. It is good to see this history on record. Matthew is honest about the lessons to be learnt from the past as well as the challenges of today. 


Marxism?


Matthew opens with Frederick Engels’ 1873 essay on
The Housing Question and connects his narrative to a Marxist account of the co-ops: their project, in this version, is to produce housing for use rather than as ‘commodity.’ This has led to a negative response to Matthew’s work from some of my former colleagues. Co-operative development was heavily opposed by Labour’s ‘hard left’ in the form of the Militant Tendency, the Marxist project which controlled Liverpool city council from 1983 to 1985. The co-ops flourished, for a few years, with the backing of the Liberals in the city, Margaret Thatcher’s government and some parts of the Labour Party hostile to Militant and to its Marxist creed. 


How then to assess Matthew’s Marxist framing of his research? Engels’ essay was a critique of a solution to the ‘housing question’ advocated (said Engels) by followers of Marx’s French rival Proudhon. This solution was for all tenants of urban housing to become owner-occupiers. Engels objects on two grounds: one political, the other economic. Politically, says Engels:


In order to create the modern revolutionary class of the proletariat it was absolutely necessary to cut the umbilical cord which still bound the worker of the past to the land. … And now comes this tearful Proudhonist and bewails the driving of the workers from hearth and home as though it were a great retrogression instead of being the very first condition for their intellectual emancipation.


Economically, Engels complains, the Proudhonists depict the relationship between landlord and tenant as corresponding to that between employer and worker, and therefore another site for the expropriation of value from the worker. No, says Engels, this is a ‘leap from economic reality.’ The landlord/tenant relationship is a normal commodity transaction using the spending power the worker possesses. The site of exploitation is the capitalist place of production, where the worker is paid much less than the value of the product, and this gap is the ‘surplus value’ which accrues to the capitalist investor. There is no extraction of ‘surplus value’ in the commodity transaction known as house rent. 


Militant objects


Militant captured control of the Liverpool Labour Party and then, in 1983, gained enough wards to take over the city council. The newbuild co-ops to that point had been funded by the Housing Corporation (central government) and by the city council under Liberal-Conservative control. Militant was committed to confronting government with a demand for greatly increased housing investment. It was open to them to include an option for co-op housing in this programme. After some hesitation this option was rejected and the Liverpool Labour Party adopted a policy of ‘smashing’ the co-ops. 


Their objection to the co-ops was that they were an ‘elitist’ device for ‘queue-jumping’ – in other words, that the leaders and members saw themselves as superior to the wider body of tenants waiting for social housing, and allocated homes not strictly according to priority need but rather through selection reflecting community ties (albeit among those eligible for public housing, as the co-ops were mostly formed among residents of homes designated for slum clearance). There was some truth in these claims. 


Our passion for the co-operative model, advocated by the 1974-79 Labour government, arose, above all, from disgust at the conditions into which state housing had fallen by the 1970s. Design of vast housing estates was gratuitously crude and insensitive to people’s taste and aspirations, build quality was poor, management was lax, record keeping sometimes non-existent, and maintenance was often appalling.  Allocations policy overrode the family and community links that fostered well-being in poor neighbourhoods. The system appeared to be run primarily in the interests of the workforce, whose union representatives exercised power, through their position in the Labour Party, to influence selection of Labour council candidates.  All these concerns were familiar and shared across a wide spectrum of opinion, not least in the Labour Party. The question was about solutions. We thought consumer control and choice, within a framework of public provision, would succeed. We believed that disrupting centrally planned solutions was justified, necessary and positive. For Militant and their close allies in the Labour and council bureaucracy, the answer lay in design models based on those offered by mass-market providers like Wimpey Homes, separation of public and private space, rigour in applying needs-based allocations, and a warm embrace of the unions.


Both sides thought that they would advance socialism – Militant by confronting Thatcher with an unstoppable demand for the restoration of mass council housing; ourselves by igniting demand for community control, empowering consumers and abolishing the landlord/tenant relationship. The Right’s alternative, as it developed under Thatcher and then Major, was to empower users as individual home owners or as tenants with rights of redress; competitive tendering of maintenance contracts; and shifting the rump of public housing stock to private (typically charitable) landlords, expecting over time to eliminate state ownership of rented housing. For a few years we could use Militant’s strategy to lever support for co-operatives from the national Conservative government and from Labour leaders, eager for sticks with which to beat Militant. Eventually, 35 co-ops built around 1,800 homes. They attracted much attention for a time. Visitors like HRH Prince Charles, Prime Minister Thatcher and a succession of senior Labour figures saw confirmation of their own narratives about architecture and public housing. 


Commodity value


Pierre-Joseph Proudhon died long before Engels wrote The Housing Question; in calling the prescient project for mass owner-occupation ‘Proudhonist’, Engels recalled the dispute between Proudhon and Karl Marx a generation earlier, triggered by Proudhon’s refusal to endorse Marx’s political strategy. 180 years after the original split, a geographer writing a doctoral thesis finds it handy to frame his valuable narrative within the theories of one side of this debate. Is this just a harmless indulgence of academic fashion? Does it make sense to view the coops through the lens of the socialism of the century before last?  Proudhon and Engels agreed that the problem was that capitalism conferred a commodity value on urban space which put it beyond the reach of wage earners, so Matthew sees the coops as solving this by removing the commodity element from land development (Proudhon’s solution, not Engels’). 


This analysis disregards one fundamental fact of the landscape Matthew surveys: the land developed by the co-ops generally (not always) had no commodity value to speak of. Why so? The area of south-central Liverpool was developed in the later nineteenth century as housing for the more affluent working class, at a time when the normal tenure was private rental. After the first world war, private rents were controlled down to a level that eventually excluded any possibility of investment in the stock. Then the area was ‘red-lined’ – condemned to demolition on the basis of the self-fulfilling prophecy that it comprised ‘slums.’ So the commodity value of the homes was systematically abolished by the state. This impoverished the owner occupiers living there. Private tenants found cheap housing with strong community links (a word with the rent collector serving to find a home for a relative) but in unacceptable conditions. State investment was then the answer. The strenuously articulated demand for consumer control over the terms of that investment was the basis of the co-operative movement that Matthew analyses. The problem with the attempt to depict this in ‘Marxist’ terms is that it lets the Left off the hook. The state is (according to Marx and Engels’ Communist Manifesto) the ‘committee for managing the common affairs of the whole bourgeoisie’ - so its huge role in reshaping the housing market, using its regulatory and financial might to bring ruin on some neighbourhoods, while enhancing the commodity value of other housing stock, is merely a response to the needs of capitalism. But in fact this drastic remodelling of the housing market was, in large measure, the outworking of the influence of nineteenth century socialist thought, not least that of Proudhon and Engels. The Left can make progress only when it gets to grips with its own history – the history, one might say, of its own crimes. 


As for ‘decommodification’, Engels might be surprised to hear that a struggle by a collective working-class undertaking first to own, and then to confer value upon, parcels of worthless land is about ‘decommodification.’ Rather its interests are served (surely) by capturing and then reinvesting commodity value. Matthew shows, in his account of one well-known example, that a heroic attempt at such an approach failed because the needed governance skills were lacking. More widely the co-ops remain essentially inward-looking and conservative, unwilling to risk an expansive reinvestment strategy. 


The co-operative approach was not sustained under the Labour government elected in 1997: its policies reinforced the principle that any social home must be let to the applicant in most need at the point of letting, effectively making illegal the long-term pre-allocation of tenancies on which the model depends. Still, the Merseyside homes the coops built remain today, sometimes patches of order amidst the chaos of inner-city decline, many still under co-operative control.


Altogether, according to the Confederation of Co-operative Housing, 200,000 homes in the UK are owned and/or managed by co-ops – under 1% of the total stock. Can the model break out of this enclave to make a more mainstream contribution to housing provision? Matthew’s thesis explores part of the answer. In my view, Marxism is not helpful to his purpose. 


Hales Place - a council estate that turned into student accommodation. How?
by James Paul Lusk 22 Mar, 2021
Hales Place in Canterbury was built as a 1400 home council estate to meet the needs of families and older and disabled people. Within a few years a quarter of the homes turned into high-density student accommodation. How did this happen?
The truth about the housing crisis
by James Paul Lusk 28 Aug, 2020
We are told that the 'housing crisis' (the shortage of choice for younger home-seekers) results from limited housing stock. In fact the amount of homes has greatly increased relative to population in the last fifty years, while the real price of housing relative to income has more than doubled. So what is going on? We explain why building more homes will not solve the problem
by Paul Lusk 01 Jan, 2020
Older blogs on the Ashers bakery 'gay cake' case, why Tim Farron's own colleagues hung him out to dry, how Care lost May an election, and more.
Other blog posts
Share by: